The Paul, Weiss Antitrust Practice advises clients on a full range of global antitrust matters, including antitrust regulatory clearance, government investigations, private litigation, and counseling and compliance. The firm represents clients before antitrust and competition authorities in the United States, the European Union, the United Kingdom and other jurisdictions around the world.
Second Circuit Applies Rule of Reason to Uphold Preliminary Injunction Preventing Manufacturer from Removing Alzheimer’s Drug from Market
June 3, 2015 download PDF
In State of New York v. Actavis plc, No.
14-4624-cv (2d Cir. May 22, 2015), the United States Court of
Appeals for the Second Circuit addressed "a novel question" of
antitrust law: "under what circumstances does conduct by a
monopolist to perpetuate patent exclusivity through successive
products, commonly known as 'product hopping,' violate the Sherman
Act." Slip Op. at 6. The case involved a drug
manufacturer(1) that planned to discontinue the manufacture
and sale of a twice-daily immediate-release version of an
Alzheimer's drug-for which the patent was about to expire-with the
goal of switching patients to a once-daily extended-release version
of the same drug covered by a patent that will not expire until
2029. By doing so, the manufacturer hoped to avoid losing
substantial market share to generic manufacturers that would be
able to begin selling the immediate-release version of the drug
upon the expiration of its patent. The District Court issued
a preliminary injunction that required the manufacturer to continue
making the immediate-release version of the drug available to
patients at the same price until thirty days after generic versions
of the immediate-release drug become available. In an
extensive 60-page decision, the Second Circuit-focusing its
antitrust analysis on the "particular structure and circumstances"
of the pharmaceutical industry-concluded that the District Court
did not abuse its discretion and upheld the injunction.
As discussed below, the Second Circuit's decision is noteworthy
because the standard for determining when this type of conduct
violates the Sherman Act is evolving, and the remedy-requiring a
patent holder to continue manufacturing a product for a period of
time in order to facilitate competition in the product market once
its patent expires-is unusual. Subsequent court decisions
will need to determine the extent to which this decision is limited
to the particular facts and circumstances presented by the
regulation of the pharmaceutical industry, or whether it should be
extended more broadly to similar conduct in other contexts.
Background
The Hatch-Waxman Act, which was intended to "serve the dual
purposes of both encouraging generic drug competition in order to
lower drug prices and incentivizing brand drug manufacturers to
innovate through patent extensions," slip op. at 8, provides
important background for the court's decision. Of particular
relevance here, the Hatch-Waxman Act permits a drug manufacturer
that wants to market a generic version of an FDA approved branded
drug to file an abbreviated application to expedite the FDA
approval process for the generic version of the drug.
Id. at 8-10. As the Second Circuit explained, "[b]y
enabling generic manufacturers to 'piggy back' on a brand drug's
scientific studies, Hatch-Waxman 'speeds the introduction of
low-cost generic drugs to market, thereby furthering drug
competition.'" Id. at 9-10 (quoting F.T.C.
v. Actavis, Inc., 133 S. Ct. 2223, 2228 (2013)).
The interplay between the Hatch-Waxman Act and state "drug
substitution laws" is also important: All 50 states and the
District of Columbia have enacted laws that "either permit or
require pharmacists to dispense a therapeutically equivalent,
lower-cost generic drug in place of a brand drug absent express
direction from the prescribing physician." Id. at
10. Taken together, the Hatch-Waxman Act and state drug
substitution laws mean that a brand drug manufacturer is forced to
confront what is commonly known in the industry as the "patent
cliff": when a brand drug's patent exclusivity ends and
generic versions-supported by state drug substitution laws-enter
the market, "the brand drug often loses more than 80 to 90% of the
market within six months." Id. at 17.
In an attempt to avoid the patent cliff that it expected to face
when the patent on its twice-daily immediate-release version of an
Alzheimer's drug ("Namenda IR") would expire in July 2015, the
brand drug manufacturer devised a so-called "product-hopping"
strategy whereby it would stop manufacturing and selling Namenda IR
before its patent expired, anticipating that physicians would
switch their patients to the newer once-daily extended-release
version of Namenda ("Namenda XR") that would remain on patent until
2029. According to the court, causing patients to make this
switch to Namenda XR before the exclusivity period on Namenda IR
expired would effectively "prevent generic substitution" of the
generic version of Namenda IR after the patent on Namenda IR
expired and therefore deprive generic manufacturers of "the only
cost-efficient means of competing available to generic
manufacturers." Id. at 39-41.(2)
The court found that this was the case because, among other things,
transaction costs would make it unlikely that patients having
switched to Namenda XR would "reverse commute" and switch back to
the generic version of Namenda IR. Id. at 23,
41-43.
On September 15, 2014, New York State filed a complaint that
included monopolization and attempted monopolization claims under
Section 2 of the Sherman Act and sought to enjoin the manufacturer
from removing Namenda IR from the market. On December 15,
2014, after a five-day hearing, the district court issued a
preliminary injunction ordering the manufacturer to make Namenda IR
"available on the same terms and conditions applicable since July
21, 2013." Id. at 24. The manufacturer
appealed.
Second Circuit Opinion
The Second Circuit, applying a heightened standard requiring New
York to show a "substantial likelihood of success on the merits,"
determined that the district court had not abused its discretion in
entering the injunction. After concluding that it was
appropriate for the district court to apply a "rule of reason"
analysis to New York's claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act,
the court stated that "[w]ell-established case law makes clear that
product redesign is anticompetitive when it coerces consumers and
impedes competition." Id. at 33-35.(3)
Citing its 1979 decision in Berkey Photo, Inc. v.
Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263 (2d Cir. 1979), the court
declared that that "when a monopolist combines product withdrawal
with some other conduct, the overall effect of which is to coerce
consumers rather than persuade them on the merits, and to impede
competition, its actions are anticompetitive under the Sherman
Act." Slip Op. at 35-36 (emphasis in original) (citations
omitted).
Applying that principle, the court determined that the withdrawal
of Namenda IR from the market constituted coercion of
consumers: given the "transaction costs" of switching
Alzheimer's patients from one medication to another, the drug
manufacturer had functionally deprived consumers of the ability to
choose between the generic version of Namenda IR and Namenda XR
once the generic version of Namenda IR entered the market.
Id. at 37-39; see also id. at 41-43. The
court also found that the conduct was likely to be exclusionary
because the chief means of competition in the pharmaceutical market
consisted of "[p]rice competition at the pharmacy, facilitated by
state substitution laws," and by preventing those substitution laws
from operating, the drug manufacturer had deprived generic
manufacturers of "the only cost-efficient means of competing
available" to them. Id. at 39-47.
The court next rejected as pretextual the drug manufacturer's
proffered procompetitive justifications for withdrawing Namenda IR,
citing evidence that withdrawing Namenda IR made economic sense
only because of the "benefit derived from eliminating generic
competition." Id. at 49. The court also
forcefully rejected an argument that the drug manufacturer's
"patent rights under Namenda IR and Namenda XR shield [it] from
antitrust liability," concluding that the manufacturer's actions
had gone beyond the scope of what its patent rights allowed
it. Id. at 51-53.
Finally, the court determined that New York had established
irreparable harm to consumers based on higher prices they would
have to pay if the drug manufacturer could compel patients to use
Namenda XR before the generic version of Namenda IR became
available. The court concluded that some of this harm might
not be recoverable in damages (e.g., harm to indirect
purchasers) and that, regardless, calculating the economic damage
to consumers would be a sufficiently complex task that the damage
could be viewed as irreparable. Id. at 54-59.
Implications
As the Second Circuit noted, the question of whether "product
hopping" violates the Sherman Act is one of first impression in the
circuit courts. Id. at 6. The court's decision
is therefore likely to have significant influence in this evolving
area of antitrust law. Although the conduct at issue in this
appeal and the Second Circuit's analysis were clearly shaped by the
unique regulatory structure created by the Hatch-Waxman Act and
state drug substitution laws, it remains to be seen whether courts
will apply a similar analysis outside the pharmaceutical regulatory
context. Courts will in the future likely have to answer
difficult questions about the extent to which an actual or
potential monopolist may have a duty to refrain from introducing
product improvements or other modifications if the effect would be
to increase transaction costs for rivals and potentially discourage
competition, and if so, what the appropriate remedy should
be. Until courts have had an opportunity to address those
questions, it remains to be seen whether the Second Circuit's
decision will become mainstream Section 2 doctrine, or will instead
be considered "at or near the outer boundary of [Section 2]
liability." Verizon Comms. Inc. v. Law Offices
of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 409 (2004) (describing
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp.,
472 U.S. 585 (1985), and discussing the extent to which the duty to
deal with competitors recognized in Aspen Skiing was at or
near the limits of liability under Section 2 of the Sherman
Act).
(1) Although there were two defendants in the case on
appeal-Actavis plc and its subsidiary Forest Laboratories,
LLC-these defendants are collectively referred to as the "drug
manufacturer" for the sake of simplicity.
(2) Differences between Namenda IR and Namenda XR would be
sufficient to prevent pharmacists from substituting the generic
version of Namenda IR for Namenda XR under "most, if not all,"
states' drug substitution laws. See id. at 16-18
& n.15.
(3) It was uncontested on appeal that the relevant product market
was the market for memantine-based products, of which the drug
manufacturer was the sole manufacturer. Id. at 14-15 &
n.11. As a result, the parties also did not dispute that the
drug manufacturer possessed monopoly power. Id. at 30.