The Paul, Weiss Antitrust Practice advises clients on a full range of global antitrust matters, including antitrust regulatory clearance, government investigations, private litigation, and counseling and compliance. The firm represents clients before antitrust and competition authorities in the United States, the European Union, the United Kingdom and other jurisdictions around the world.
Upward Pressure on Price Analysis: Issues and Implications for Merger Policy
August 1, 2010
By Joseph J. Simons and Malcolm B. Coate *
Note: This article originally appeared in the August 2010 issue
of the European Competition Journal published by Hart
Publishing.
» Purchase the final PDF of this article
Farrell and Shapiro's Upward Pressure on Price (UPP) framework is
an innovative and elegant technique designed to evaluate mergers in
differentiated product markets. The authors advance their
approach primarily as a screen for unilateral effects cases,
although others suggest that UPP might be implemented to create a
presumption of anticompetitive effect. We raise two concerns
with the methodology. First, there is no empirical evidence
confirming that the method can reliably predict whether a merger is
likely to increase price and second, UPP analysis screens or
presumes as anticompetitive a very large universe of mergers.
We develop simple simulations illustrating that a UPP- based
approach would identify mergers as potentially problematic at
levels that have not attracted serious scrutiny from any major
antitrust authority in decades. Farrell and Shapiro's UPP
methodology also has potential as an alternative to merger
simulation. Here, we are cautiously optimistic that UPP
analysis can replace the complex simulation models introduced by
economists over the last 20 years. However, simulation
analysis should not be used in any particular case without
exogenous evidence confirming the basic predictions.
A. INTRODUCTION
For over fifteen years, analysts have searched for a better method
to evaluate the potential competitive effects from anticompetitive
mergers involving differentiated products. (Footnote
1) The traditional analysis involves the definition of a
relevant market and the use of concentration statistics adapted to
the evaluation of unilateral effects. (Footnote
2) Some economists, however, have suggested dropping the
concept of the market from the antitrust lexicon and directly
estimating the unilateral competitive effect. (Footnote 3) Instead of applying a structural
market analysis, merger simulation would predict the price increase
likely to stem from the merger under review. Within this
approach, other types of evidence might rebut the simulation
results, but, absent sufficient immunizing evidence, the simulation
results would prove the violation.
These economic models have not been very successful for multiple
reasons. (Footnote 4) Even the simplest
simulation requires detailed parameterization, involving for
example, reasonably precise estimates of a demand system including
own and cross price elasticities along with predicted marginal cost
savings. Thus, the methodology does not give rise to a viable
initial screening structure to separate innocuous from potentially
problematic mergers. Moreover, even with a full
investigation, parameterization is often problematic. Unless
rich data sets are available, simulation offers little
insight. Finally, even for retail consumer products where
rich data sets are available, simulation models have not been shown
to reliably predict price effects from mergers and thus, standing
alone, likely would not pass a Daubert test in the United States.
(Footnote 5)
In 2008, Farrell and Shapiro (F&S) introduced the Upward
Pressure on Price (UPP) index to evaluate the potential for
competitive concerns in differentiated products markets. (Footnote 6) In its simple form, the technique
purports to identify mergers that might lead to higher
prices. In a more complex form, UPP analysis seems to address
some of the problems presented by merger simulation.
The basic UPP index focuses on measuring the upward pressure that a
merger would place on price as a function of diversion ratios,
margins, and efficiencies. Farrell and Shapiro expect the
analyst to be able to estimate diversion ratios and price-cost
margins, and illustrate how the calculation will work with 10 %
marginal cost savings. Mergers with a positive UPP
coefficient would require a more detailed investigation of their
likely anticompetitive effects or as others have suggested, a
material increase in UPP would create a presumption of
illegality. (Footnote 7)
Proposed revisions for both the United Kingdom (UK) and the United
States (US) Merger Guidelines integrate UPP-related variables into
the merger review process. (Footnote 8)
The UK draft notes the diversion ratio is "a useful measure of the
ability of the second product to constrain the prices of the first
product" (at 4.88a) and identifies high profit margins as an
indicator variable for the likelihood of a price increase (at
4.88b). These two variables, diversions and margins, sit at
the core of the UPP analysis. The US draft Guidelines raise
similar issues. Higher diversion ratios are expected to
predict a greater probability of anticompetitive unilateral pricing
(at Section 6.1, on page 21). The US discussion then mentions
the margin between price and cost as a variable that measures the
lost profits from a price increase. The Upward Pressure on
Price construct is noted as one of the factors that can be
considered in a merger review. While both Guidelines detail
other variables likely to affect the competitive analysis, it
appears that the UPP construct could play an important role in
merger analysis on both sides of the Atlantic.
We have serious concerns with Farrell and Shapiro's screen and even
greater concerns with suggestions that the UPP methodology be used
to create a presumption of anticompetitive effect. Absent
efficiencies, the UPP index predicts that every horizontal merger
has an anticompetitive effect and thus every horizontal merger
could appear to be illegal. (Footnote 9)
Farrell and Shapiro recognize this result as extreme and propose
using a "standard deduction" for efficiencies, which tends to
offset the price increasing effect. (Footnote
10) As an example, they discuss a very generous 10%
marginal cost efficiencies deduction.
Most antitrust enforcement authorities, however, have historically
been skeptical, if not hostile to efficiency defenses, so that
permitting such a large standard deduction for efficiencies would
be quite a departure from current practice. (Footnote
11) Moreover, the use of a standard deduction does not
change the fact that the UPP index has not been proven to generate
reliable predictions. Using a standard deduction that itself
has no empirical basis would not be much different than just adding
a fudge factor to hide the fact that otherwise, the approach always
produces a price effect. Finally, in our experience, Federal
Trade Commission (FTC) recognition of merger specific marginal cost
savings in the range of 10% is rare, if not unprecedented. As
we show below, even assuming such a high level of efficiencies, the
approach suggested by Farrell and Shapiro would identify as
potentially problematic a large number of mergers that have not
attracted serious scrutiny from the antitrust enforcement
authorities in decades.
With respect to a more fully-parameterized version of Farrell and
Shapiro's UPP model, it may be able to function as a simple
simulation for the competitive effects of a merger. (Footnote 12) The methodology, parameterized
with diversions, margins, efficiencies, pass-through coefficients,
and benchmarks for tolerable price increases, is a more transparent
method of evaluating post-merger price effects than pre-existing
simulation techniques. Moreover, the simulation concept is
generalizable to other models that purport to measure upward
pressure on price.
Although UPP based simulation represents a significant improvement
over the pre-existing simulation methodologies, it suffers from the
same fundamental verification problem that undermines all merger
simulation structures. That is, UPP analysis lacks a history of
successful prediction of post-merger price effects needed to
scientifically predict the price effects of mergers.
Accordingly, absent a showing that the UPP analysis is likely to
predict price effects correctly in the industry in question, the
methodology would be unscientific and thus should not be admissible
in court. In cases where other evidence (e.g. natural
experiments) can be used to demonstrate the likelihood of a
specific price effect, however, it may be possible to calibrate a
UPP simulation based on that other evidence and enable the model to
balance the impact of structural change with merger-related
efficiencies.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. It starts with
some background material to tie the UPP methodology to the better
known tool of merger simulation. The limitations on
simulation are introduced to highlight why an alternative approach
would be of value. The third section provides an overview of
Farrell and Shapiro's UPP screen. Tables are generated to
illustrate the link between the results of an UPP analysis and
diversions or market structure, given first, no efficiencies and
then, ten % marginal cost savings. If used as a screen for
investigative purposes only, we show the approach would tag a very
large universe of mergers as potentially problematic, thus failing
to isolate the mergers most appropriate for further review.
Alternatively, if used to create a presumption of anticompetitive
effect, the UPP model could support a dramatic increase in merger
challenges, marking a stark contrast with enforcement over the last
several decades. Section D addresses the ability to use
UPP models to simulate the competitive effects of a merger in a
differentiated products business. We conclude that UPP-based
simulation holds limited promise as a technique for balancing
clearly demonstrated efficiencies and empirically-demonstrated
anticompetitive effects. Section E summarizes our
observations.
B. BACKGROUND ON THE
THEORY
The UPP model is grounded in the standard Nash-Bertrand
differentiated products analysis that has become prevalent in the
economics literature over the last twenty years. These
theoretical models impose a tight mathematical structure on the
competitive process in an industry and then generate implications
for the effect of a merger by re-optimizing the equilibrium given
the change in structure caused by the merger. (Footnote 13) Parameters include coefficients
of the relevant demand system (sufficient to give rise to own and
cross elasticities and the associated diversion ratios), pre-merger
prices, and merger-related marginal cost efficiencies. Once
parameterized, a relatively straight-forward optimization scheme
generates predictions on the price increases caused by the
merger. (Footnote 14) Absent
sufficient efficiencies, these models predict price increases for
all horizontal mergers no matter how fragmented the market.
As a general proposition, the price of the product sold by the
smaller of the merging parties will increase by more than the price
of the product sold by the larger of the merging parties. (Footnote 15) Prices of third parties increase
by significantly less than the prices of the merged parties.
Cost efficiencies exert downward pressure on the merged firm's
price, and if the efficiencies are large enough, prices will
fall.
Nash-Bertrand simulation models can be implemented in a range of
situations. Economists can estimate the necessary
coefficients by imposing Logit structures when minimal data is
available or more general AIDS assumptions when much more detailed
pricing data can be obtained. Current cost
conditions fall out of the pre-merger equilibrium calculation, but
are expected to match the empirical evidence as part of the
technical validation of the model. (Footnote
16) Predictions for post-merger price increases often
depend on the particular demand structure chosen, but the
robustness of these price effects can be examined by changing the
specification of the model and/or tweaking the parameters of the
model. Of particular interest is the effect of cost changes
on the magnitude of the post-merger price changes. It is
generally recognized that merger simulation represents one approach
to balance the anticompetitive effects of a structural change with
the pro-competitive benefits of merger-specific efficiencies.
Merger analysts know simulations must be followed with an
evaluation of repositioning and entry impediments to ensure that
these considerations do not trump the prediction of a competitive
concern.
Although the methodology was fully developed in the 1990s, merger
simulation has not caught on in the United States. While
Budzinski and Ruhmer report merger simulation is one of the tools
used by the enforcement agencies, (Footnote 17)
no court has accepted the analytical approach. (Footnote 18) This failure is not surprising,
because simulation analysis suffers from a number of draw-backs. (Footnote 19)
First, the black box nature of the modeling structure limits the
ability of even experienced antitrust lawyers to actually
understand the analysis. The computations start with a set of
assumptions and derive a vector of price increases linked to the
change in market structure caused by the merger. Unless the
price changes are trivial or obvious evidence rebuts the
presumption of concern, the merger is seen as anticompetitive. (Footnote 20) Moreover, the magnitude of the
price effect can change substantially as the analyst imposes
different modeling structures on the data. (Footnote
21)
Second, simulation analysis is often divorced from the concept of a
relevant market. While theorists argue demand simulation
generates price effects without the need to define markets, failure
to ground the simulation in a relevant market makes it particularly
difficult to fully evaluate the price predictions. If the
simulation model does not represent a relevant market, can the
analyst complete the market-based repositioning and entry analyses
needed to support the final conclusion that the merger
substantially lessens competition within some (undefined) area of
rivalry?
Third, all simulation models impose substantial data requirements
on the analyst. This significantly limits the applicability
of the analysis to markets in which rich sources of data are
available. While the analyst can impose structure to reduce
data requirements, these structural assumptions run the risk of
introducing error into the analysis. (Footnote
22) Moreover, to the extent that data limitations
introduce estimation error into the analysis, the price predictions
may not be accurate. (Footnote 23)
Fourth, by focusing the competitive analysis on the price set by
each firm, the simulation methodology appears to ignore more
complex competitive processes. For example, non-price
competition with respect to the design, promotion, or placement
(distribution) of the products sold in the market may have a
significant effect on customer decisions. Dynamic links
between price and the other variables are also assumed away,
regardless of the factual situation. Finally, and most
importantly, prices may be set through direct customer-supplier
negotiation, suggesting producers do not have the ability to set a
single price for their differentiated product. (Footnote 24) While the simulation methodology
could be adjusted to address some of these problems, the analysis
would become even more dependent on the assumed parameters. (Footnote 25)
All these problems likely contribute to the inability of most
simulation models to predict post-merger prices. (Footnote 26) In effect, these models are not
generalizing scientific theories, because their lack of broad
empirical support implies simulation modeling fails the "market
test" of science. Instead, these models are possibility (or
exemplifying) theories of economics, defining what might happen,
rather than predicting what will happen. Of course,
simulation may still remain useful on a case-by-case basis, when
natural experiment evidence is compatible with the predictions of
the model.
C. UPP ANALYSIS OF MERGERS
Farrell and Shapiro introduced UPP analysis to focus on the
pressures for unilateral price effects while avoiding both the need
for market definition and the much greater data requirements of
traditional merger simulations. As noted below, if the
merging firms can be considered symmetric, UPP analysis can be
undertaken with just evidence on diversion ratios and price-cost
margins, along with an assumption for efficiencies. While
diversions interact with margins to create pressure to raise
prices, efficiencies serve to reduce the upward pressure on
price. Once accounting for efficiencies, it is possible to
compute the net upward pressure on price. (Footnote
27)
The F&S UPP technique observes that every horizontal merger in
a differentiated product market exerts upward pressure on price,
because the merged firm is able to recover the margin on sales
gained by one of the merged entities when the other entity raises
price. Likewise, if one entity lowers price to gain share,
the merger makes that price decrease more costly, because the
merged firm recognizes the loss in margin to the partner entity
caused by the price decrease. (Footnote
28) Farrell and Shapiro focus on this cannibalization
effect and estimate the initial effect (tax, in their terminology)
of a one unit increase in output as the diversion rate to the
merger partner multiplied by the gross margin of a unit of
production by the merger partner.
Farrell and Shapiro note the cannibalization effect will be at
least partially offset by the merger-specific efficiencies achieved
by the entity changing price. Here, F&S propose 10 % cost
savings as an example of the "standard deduction" for cost savings
achieved by the firm. Thus, what-ever upward pressure that
exists to raise price will be offset to some degree by the marginal
cost reductions. Equation 1 follows Farrell and Shapiro
and combines the cannibalization effect with the efficiency
allowance and an assumption of Nash-Bertrand competition to define
an inequality that determines whether the firm faces upward pricing
pressure.
1) D12 * (P2 - C2) >
E1*C1
where the diversion ratio from firm 1 to firm 2 is D12, the P's and
C's are the prices and marginal costs of firms 1 and 2 and E1 is
firm 1's standard deduction for efficiencies.
Schmalensee, following the original Werden analysis, suggests a
slightly different equation reproduced below as equation 2. (Footnote 29) Because costs fall after the
merger for both merger partners, the margin of firm 2 must be
adjusted to reflect the lower post-merger costs. Here, E will
be used to represent marginal cost savings (as both firms are
credited with the same standard deduction for efficiencies).
While Farrell and Shapiro prefer their equation, we agree with
Schmalensee that efficiency adjustments should be made on both
sides of the equation.
2) D12 * (P2 - (C2 - E*C2)) >
E*C1
An analogous equation exists for the other merged entity.
Imposing symmetry assumptions on the firms, along with cost and
price equality justifies Equation 3, with D considered the
diversion parameter and M considered the pre-merger price-cost
margin relevant to both firms. (Footnote
30)
3) D > E * (1-M)*
(1-D)/M
To explore the implications of this model, we rearrange terms to
obtain a slightly adjusted equation for the percentage upward
pressure on price (UPP*/P). If equation 4 is met, then the
merger is considered to exert upward pressure on price after
correcting for efficiencies and thus would trigger the screen for
anticompetitive effect. A comparable calculation is made for
Farrell and Shapiro's UPP model and it is given in the
Appendix. Table 1-b and Table 2, introduced below, are
re-estimated in the appendix to show the choice of UPP* or UPP has
little effect on the outcome of the analysis.
4) UPP*/P = M * D - E * (1-M) * (1-D)
> 0
Equation 4 defines a very simple formula for the UPP model.
Tables 1-a and 1-b evaluate the model for given values of the
margin and diversion parameters, first when the efficiency index is
set to 0 and then when it is set to Farrell and Shapiro's example
of 10 % savings. (Footnote 31)
Table 1-a shows all mergers in differentiated products result in a
positive UPP, placing upward pressure on price. This
illustrates that the approach always predicts the merger will lead
to higher prices when efficiencies are not present. (Footnote 32) Given the symmetry assumption,
the merger would generate the same upward price pressure for both
merger partners. Thus, without efficiencies, merger enforcers
could be very active in differentiated products markets.
Table 1-a: UPP* Model by Margin and Diversion, No Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
Diversion |
|
|
|
|
|
0.10 |
0.15 |
0.20 |
0.25 |
0.30 |
0.35 |
0.40 |
|
0.90 |
0.090 |
0.135 |
0.180 |
0.225 |
0.270 |
0.315 |
0.360 |
|
0.80 |
0.080 |
0.120 |
0.160 |
0.200 |
0.240 |
0.280 |
0.320 |
|
0.70 |
0.070 |
0.105 |
0.140 |
0.175 |
0.210 |
0.245 |
0.280 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.060 |
0.090 |
0.120 |
0.150 |
0.180 |
0.210 |
0.240 |
|
0.50 |
0.050 |
0.075 |
0.100 |
0.125 |
0.150 |
0.175 |
0.200 |
|
0.40 |
0.040 |
0.060 |
0.080 |
0.100 |
0.120 |
0.140 |
0.160 |
|
0.30 |
0.030 |
0.045 |
0.060 |
0.075 |
0.090 |
0.105 |
0.120 |
|
0.20 |
0.020 |
0.030 |
0.040 |
0.050 |
0.060 |
0.070 |
0.080 |
|
0.10 |
0.010 |
0.015 |
0.020 |
0.025 |
0.030 |
0.035 |
0.040 |
Table 1-b: UPP* Model by Margin and Diversion, 10 % Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
Diversion |
|
|
|
|
|
0.10 |
0.15 |
0.20 |
0.25 |
0.30 |
0.35 |
0.40 |
|
0.90 |
0.081 |
0.127 |
0.172 |
0.218 |
0.263 |
0.309 |
0.354 |
|
0.80 |
0.062 |
0.103 |
0.144 |
0.185 |
0.226 |
0.267 |
0.308 |
|
0.70 |
0.043 |
0.080 |
0.116 |
0.153 |
0.189 |
0.226 |
0.262 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.024 |
0.056 |
0.088 |
0.120 |
0.152 |
0.184 |
0.216 |
|
0.50 |
0.005 |
0.033 |
0.060 |
0.088 |
0.115 |
0.143 |
0.170 |
|
0.40 |
-0.014 |
0.009 |
0.032 |
0.055 |
0.078 |
0.101 |
0.124 |
|
0.30 |
-0.033 |
-0.014 |
0.004 |
0.023 |
0.041 |
0.061 |
0.078 |
|
0.20 |
-0.052 |
-0.038 |
-0.024 |
-0.010 |
0.004 |
0.018 |
0.032 |
|
0.10 |
-0.071 |
-0.061 |
-0.052 |
-0.042 |
-0.033 |
-0.023 |
-0.014 |
Table 1-b adds the standard deduction for efficiencies to the
simulation. A quick review of the table shows that enforcers
could still be much more active than would be consistent with
current practice. (Footnote 33) UPP
would be positive for all mergers involving firms with 50% margins
or higher and for substantial number of mergers with margins of
over 30%.
Table 2 links the F&S results to market structure.
The analyses take assumptions on the number of competitors and
translate them into diversion ratios that would result assuming
each competitor is equally situated (i.e., volume diverts equally
to each other competitor assuming a price increase by one of the
firms). For example, a 20% diversion ratio implies that there would
be six equally situated pre-merger competitors. A merger would
reduce the number of competitors by one. (Footnote 34) Table 2-a illustrates that
(without efficiencies) all horizontal mergers are predicted to
raise price under this approach. For example, there would be
a positive UPP of 1.1 % for situations involving a merger in a
market with ten rivals when the firms have margins of only 10%. (Footnote 35)
Table 2-a: UPP* Model by Margins and Rivals, No Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
|
Rivals |
|
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
|
0.90 |
0.900 |
0.450 |
0.300 |
0.225 |
0.180 |
0.150 |
0.129 |
0.113 |
0.100 |
|
0.80 |
0.800 |
0.400 |
0.267 |
0.200 |
0.160 |
0.133 |
0.114 |
0.100 |
0.089 |
|
0.70 |
0.700 |
0.350 |
0.233 |
0.175 |
0.140 |
0.117 |
0.100 |
0.088 |
0.078 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.600 |
0.300 |
0.200 |
0.150 |
0.120 |
0.100 |
0.086 |
0.075 |
0.067 |
|
0.50 |
0.500 |
0.250 |
0.167 |
0.125 |
0.100 |
0.083 |
0.071 |
0.063 |
0.056 |
|
0.40 |
0.400 |
0.200 |
0.133 |
0.100 |
0.080 |
0.067 |
0.057 |
0.050 |
0.044 |
|
0.30 |
0.300 |
0.150 |
0.100 |
0.075 |
0.060 |
0.050 |
0.043 |
0.038 |
0.033 |
|
0.20 |
0.200 |
0.100 |
0.067 |
0.050 |
0.040 |
0.033 |
0.029 |
0.025 |
0.022 |
|
0.10 |
0.100 |
0.050 |
0.033 |
0.025 |
0.020 |
0.017 |
0.014 |
0.013 |
0.011 |
Table 2-b: UPP* Model by Margins and Rivals, 10 % Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
|
Rivals |
|
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
|
0.90 |
0.900 |
0.445 |
0.293 |
0.218 |
0.172 |
0.142 |
0.120 |
0.104 |
0.091 |
|
0.80 |
0.800 |
0.390 |
0.253 |
0.185 |
0.144 |
0.117 |
0.097 |
0.083 |
0.071 |
|
0.70 |
0.700 |
0.335 |
0.213 |
0.153 |
0.116 |
0.092 |
0.074 |
0.061 |
0.051 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.600 |
0.280 |
0.173 |
0.120 |
0.088 |
0.067 |
0.051 |
0.040 |
0.031 |
|
0.50 |
0.500 |
0.225 |
0.133 |
0.088 |
0.060 |
0.042 |
0.029 |
0.019 |
0.011 |
|
0.40 |
0.400 |
0.170 |
0.093 |
0.055 |
0.032 |
0.017 |
0.006 |
-0.003 |
-0.009 |
|
0.30 |
0.300 |
0.115 |
0.053 |
0.023 |
0.004 |
-0.008 |
-0.017 |
-0.024 |
-0.029 |
|
0.20 |
0.200 |
0.060 |
0.013 |
-0.010 |
-0.024 |
-0.033 |
-0.040 |
-0.045 |
-0.049 |
|
0.10 |
0.100 |
0.005 |
-0.027 |
-0.043 |
-0.052 |
-0.058 |
-0.063 |
-0.066 |
-0.069 |
Table 2-b shows the results assuming a substantial 10% standard
deduction for efficiencies. Even with this deduction,
however, enforcers could still be extremely active. For
example, a merger involving two of ten firms produces a
positive UPP as long as the margins are 50% or higher. UPP
would be positive for instances involving six equally situated
pre-merger entities with margins as low as 30%. This approach
could essentially condemn six-to-five mergers where margins would
be considered moderate at best. (Footnote
36) For higher margins, (those usually applied in
differentiated products markets) the approach would be much more
aggressive. Table 2 makes clear that the UPP approach even
with the 10% standard efficiencies deduction would mark a
substantial break with historical enforcement patterns over the
last two decades (Footnote 37), let alone the
outcome of recently litigated US merger cases. (Footnote 38)
Tables 1 and 2 both illustrate a fundamental concern with the
Farrell and Shapiro screen - it identifies as potentially
problematic far more mergers than would be challenged or even
investigated under the enforcement standards that have existed for
more than 20 years. Perhaps these enforcement standards
have not been appropriate and merger policy has been far too
lenient over this time period. But if that were the case, we
should expect to see a very large universe of consummated mergers
that produced price effects over that time. At least for now,
no such evidence exists.
Simply tweaking the Farrell and Shapiro structure to impose a
threshold tolerance level in addition to (or as a replacement for)
the efficiency defense does not solve the problem, because such a
model would still lack empirical verification. (Footnote 39) This problem also precludes
others from using UPP to establish a presumption. While it is
premature to conclude that is it impossible to define an UPP based
approach that could reliably predict the price effects of certain
mergers, such a model does not exist today. Thus, a basis to
support the use of UPP to create a generalized screen for
anticompetitive effects is lacking, as is its use to create a
presumption of anticompetitive effect.
D. UPP-BASED MERGER SIMULATION
Farrell and Shapiro's generic UPP methodology also represents a new
tool that can address the problems faced by merger simulation
models when trying to illustrate competitive concerns. (Footnote 40) Equation 5 defines a variant of
the Farrell and Shapiro model (UPP-FS) with G considered the
requirement for a significant price increase and R taken as the
pass-through rate. In addition to estimating both the
price-cost margin (M) and the symmetric diversion (D), the analyst
must measure both efficiencies (E) and pass-through (R). Only
the tolerance level for the price increase is assumed. (Footnote 41)
5) UPP*/P = M * D - E * (1-M) * (1-D)
> G/R
Upward pressure on price can be transformed into a price effect by
multiplying both sides of the UPP equation by the pass-through
R. Equation 6 presents a representative model with R set at
the linear demand pass-through of one half.
6) % Price Simulation Effect = ½ * (M * D
- E * (1-M) * (1-D))
This formula is much simpler than any existing market simulation
structure. While the UPP model is unable to match a standard
simulation by predicting the price responses of competitors, these
price changes are generally small second-order effects and thus
probably not material. The core UPP formula focuses on
estimating the two price increases imposed by the merging firm from
the available information. And the effects of different
pass-through rates can be considered by simply setting parameter R-
to a different value. While the required material price
effect (G) needed to evaluate the simulation must be assumed, the
standard merger simulation has the same problem. Simulations only
generate post-merger price levels, leaving the analyst to determine
if the change is material. (Footnote 42)
Schmalensee suggests another UPP formulation (UPP-S), by
dividing equation 6 by one minus the diversion ratio. (Footnote 43) The basic difference between
these two UPP methodologies is that Farrell and Shapiro model the
merger's initial impact on price, while Schmalensee presents a
post-merger price effect after all the merged firm's sequential
responses occur. Farrell and Shapiro recognize that the full
effect of the upward pressure on price may be higher than their
model suggests, but prefer the simpler, more intuitive
approach. (Footnote 44) While the
simulation results are quite similar for small values of diversion,
the results may differ materially for close competitors with large
diversion ratios. For example, setting margins to .5,
efficiencies to 10 %, pass-through to .5, and diversion to 25 %
generates a 4.38 % price effect for UPP-FS and a 5.84 % price
effect for UPP-S. (Footnote 45) Thus,
choosing a modeling structure can easily impose a 33 % difference
in the predicted price effect. Higher values for margins or
diversions increase the potential variance in the
prediction. (Footnote 46) Overall, to
make accurate predictions, analysts need evidence to suggest that
they use both the correct simulation structure and
parameters.
UPP simulation does have significant advantages over the standard
simulation analysis. Any form of UPP-based simulation serves
to eliminate the black box concerns associated with the complex
merger simulation models, and simplifies the data required for
simulation. Moreover, the relative ease at which this
structure can be applied makes it more feasible to "test-drive" the
model prior to completing the detailed industry study needed to
show the model is applicable. To determine if the UPP
simulation is likely to aid in the evaluation of a merger, it is
necessary to understand the dynamics of competition in the
market. While price competition might be controlling in some
differentiated product markets, product innovation is likely to be
the essence of competition in others. When innovation is
controlling, the pricing decision becomes much more complex, thus
precluding the use of a simple Lerner index based simulation
analysis. (Footnote 47)
When price is the controlling competitive consideration, UPP
simulation merits attention. However, this paper identifies
two possible UPP simulation methodologies and we are certain that
economists can create many more. Thus, the analyst faces a
serious problem in applying the analysis, due to the need to choose
a specific model. Moreover, within any model, the predicted
price effects depend on the choice of the pass-through parameter
(R). In effect, UPP simulation can predict a very broad range
of price increases. Without some exogenous evidence to
eliminate a large number of model-parameter combinations, UPP
simulation is simply not scientific. Thus, we believe it is
necessary to exogenously confirm the results of any UPP simulation
with natural experiment data, thus demonstrating
reliability. (Footnote 48) Both the UK
and US draft Guidelines touch on the importance of this evidence in
predicting post-merger performance. (Footnote
49) And, in cases when evidence confirms the specific
price predictions of the relevant simulation, the model may prove
extremely valuable in balancing potential anticompetitive and
efficiency effects. Of course, simulation analysis will
always need to be supplemented with repositioning and entry
analysis, because these factors are exogenous to the simulation
methodology. (Footnote 50)
E. CONCLUSION
Farrell and Shapiro have introduced an innovative and elegant
methodology to move the economic analysis of mergers in a more
practical direction. Based on merger simulation concepts,
F&S focus their analysis on a few reasonably observable
variables and define a merger screening algorithm designed to
identify situations in which anticompetitive effects may be
likely. Because screening mechanisms purport to highlight
general results, they need empirical support to show the
methodology actually predicts concerns relatively well. This
empirical support is not available at this time. Moreover,
our simple simulations suggest that the UPP methodology will
identify concerns with a large class of mergers generally
considered innocuous or even pro-competitive. Until the model
is shown to predict relatively well, it is premature to put the UPP
screen to work.
Farrell and Shapiro's methodology also defines a useful algorithm
that can be used to improve merger simulation analysis.
UPP-based analysis significantly reduces the black box nature of
simulation and minimizes the data requirements. Issues remain
with evaluating when the price technique is best applied and
calibrating the simulated price increase to reflect reality.
As a possibility (exemplifying) model of economic science,
simulation requires some exogenous natural experiment evidence
(broadly defined) to confirm their predictions. Estimates of
exact price effects require more comprehensive support. If
these science-related requirements can be met, UPP analysis defines
a useful structure with which to balance likely anticompetitive
effects and efficiencies. Over time, analysts are likely to
gather experience with UPP methodology and more fully understand
the insights and limitations of the general model.
* Joseph J. Simons is a Partner in Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP and Director of the Bureau of Competition at the Federal Trade Commission from June 2001 to August 2003 and Malcolm B. Coate is an economist at the Federal Trade Commission. The authors would like to thank Jeffrey Fischer and Thomas Krattenmaker for helpful comments. The analyses and conclusions set forth in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Trade Commission, any individual Commissioner, or any Commission Bureau.
Appendix A: Calculations for the Farrell and
Shapiro UPP Structure
In the text, we slightly changed the specification of Farrell and
Shapiro's UPP model to reflect the merger-specific efficiencies
captured by the merger partner in the analysis. Here, we
return to exact Farrell and Shapiro specification and present
alternative values for the simulations in Table 1-b (Table 1-a is
invariant to the change, because the efficiency coefficient is set
to zero.). Table 2 includes a second modification; and all
the results change, when we directly allow for diversion of sales
outside the market of concern as part of the numerical
simulation.
To start, we replicate Farrell and Shapiro's equation 6
below.
A-1) D * M/(1-M) > E
Where D is the diversion for the symmetric firms, M is the margin,
and E is the exogenous efficiencies. Equation A-1 can be
rearranged to obtain the UPP equation.
A-2) UPP/P = D * M - E * (1 - M)
Other than the adjustment in the efficiency effect required to
reflect the impact of the merger partners' efficiencies on the
opportunity cost of a price change (captured by multiplying the
weighted efficiency savings by (1-D)), the UPP* equation is
identical to the UPP equation. Thus, Farrell and Shapiro's
specification should show relatively less upward pressure on price,
especially when the Diversion ratio is high.
Table A-1 presents the results of the UPP model for specific
margins and diversions. The effect on the UPP index for small
diversions is minimal. For example, for a diversion of .1 and
a margin of .6, the UPP index is reduced from 2.4 % in Table 1-b to
2.0 % in Table A1. Somewhat larger effects are observed for
higher values of the diversion ratio. Moving across the table
to a diversion of .4 (with the same margin of .6) shows an UPP
value of 21.6 % in Table 1-b and 20 % in table A1. Given the
values of the UPP index increase significantly with diversions, we
find that even though the absolute differences in the UPP values
increase with diversion, the percentage differences decline.
Overall, the implications of the two UPP specifications are
similar.
Table A1: F&S UPP Model by Margin and Diversion, 10 % Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
Diversion |
|
|
|
|
|
0.10 |
0.15 |
0.20 |
0.25 |
0.30 |
0.35 |
0.40 |
|
0.90 |
0.0800 |
0.1250 |
0.1700 |
0.2150 |
0.2600 |
0.3050 |
0.3500 |
|
0.80 |
0.0600 |
0.1000 |
0.1400 |
0.1800 |
0.2200 |
0.2600 |
0.3000 |
|
0.70 |
0.0400 |
0.0750 |
0.1100 |
0.1450 |
0.1800 |
0.2150 |
0.2500 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.0200 |
0.0500 |
0.0800 |
0.1100 |
0.1400 |
0.1700 |
0.2000 |
|
0.50 |
0.0000 |
0.0250 |
0.0500 |
0.0750 |
0.1000 |
0.1250 |
0.1500 |
|
0.40 |
-0.0200 |
0.0000 |
0.0200 |
0.0400 |
0.0600 |
0.0800 |
0.1000 |
|
0.30 |
-0.0400 |
-0.0250 |
-0.0100 |
0.0050 |
0.0200 |
0.0350 |
0.0500 |
|
0.20 |
-0.0600 |
-0.0500 |
-0.0400 |
-0.0300 |
-0.0200 |
-0.0100 |
0.0000 |
|
0.10 |
-0.0800 |
-0.0750 |
-0.0700 |
-0.0650 |
-0.0600 |
-0.0550 |
-0.0500 |
When moving from measured diversions to counts of competitors, the presentation becomes slightly more complex. Farrell and Shapiro suggest using a market recapture ratio (REC in their paper) to identify the aggregate level of diversion retained by the set of firms being modeled. Thus, the share-based diversion would be reduced by the REC coefficient (here, also .8) and the UPP values calculated. The number of rivals could be considered to represent the number of significant competitors in the market.
Table 2 is re-calculated in its entirety in Table A2, because the market recapture rate lowers all the implicit diversions (here, by 20 %) and thus reduces the upward pressure on price. When no efficiencies exist, the value for UPP falls exactly 20 %, while when efficiencies are considered, two adjustments are imposed. In addition to the same 20 % reduction in upward pricing pressure, a larger efficiency effect is imposed (because the Farrell and Shapiro methodology does not reduce efficiencies for the diversion effect (1-D)).
Table A2-a: F&S UPP Model (.8 REC) by Margins and
Rivals, No Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
|
Rivals |
|
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
|
0.90 |
0.720 |
0.360 |
0.240 |
0.180 |
0.144 |
0.120 |
0.103 |
0.090 |
0.080 |
|
0.80 |
0.640 |
0.320 |
0.213 |
0.160 |
0.128 |
0.107 |
0.091 |
0.080 |
0.071 |
|
0.70 |
0.560 |
0.280 |
0.187 |
0.140 |
0.112 |
0.093 |
0.080 |
0.070 |
0.062 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.480 |
0.240 |
0.160 |
0.120 |
0.096 |
0.080 |
0.069 |
0.060 |
0.053 |
|
0.50 |
0.400 |
0.200 |
0.133 |
0.100 |
0.080 |
0.067 |
0.057 |
0.050 |
0.044 |
|
0.40 |
0.320 |
0.160 |
0.107 |
0.080 |
0.064 |
0.053 |
0.046 |
0.040 |
0.036 |
|
0.30 |
0.240 |
0.120 |
0.080 |
0.060 |
0.048 |
0.040 |
0.034 |
0.030 |
0.027 |
|
0.20 |
0.160 |
0.080 |
0.053 |
0.040 |
0.032 |
0.027 |
0.023 |
0.020 |
0.018 |
|
0.10 |
0.080 |
0.040 |
0.027 |
0.020 |
0.016 |
0.013 |
0.011 |
0.010 |
0.009 |
Table A2-b: F&S UPP Model (.8 REC) by Margins and Rivals, 10 % Efficiencies
|
|
|
|
|
|
Rivals |
|
|
|
|
|
|
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
|
0.90 |
0.710 |
0.350 |
0.230 |
0.170 |
0.134 |
0.110 |
0.093 |
0.080 |
0.070 |
|
0.80 |
0.620 |
0.300 |
0.193 |
0.140 |
0.108 |
0.087 |
0.071 |
0.060 |
0.051 |
|
0.70 |
0.530 |
0.250 |
0.157 |
0.110 |
0.082 |
0.063 |
0.050 |
0.040 |
0.032 |
Margin |
0.60 |
0.440 |
0.200 |
0.120 |
0.080 |
0.056 |
0.040 |
0.029 |
0.020 |
0.013 |
|
0.50 |
0.350 |
0.150 |
0.083 |
0.050 |
0.030 |
0.017 |
0.007 |
0.000 |
-0.006 |
|
0.40 |
0.260 |
0.100 |
0.047 |
0.020 |
0.004 |
-0.007 |
-0.014 |
-0.020 |
-0.024 |
|
0.30 |
0.170 |
0.050 |
0.010 |
-0.010 |
-0.022 |
-0.030 |
-0.036 |
-0.040 |
-0.043 |
|
0.20 |
0.080 |
0.000 |
-0.027 |
-0.040 |
-0.048 |
-0.053 |
-0.057 |
-0.060 |
-0.062 |
|
0.10 |
-0.010 |
-0.050 |
-0.063 |
-0.070 |
-0.074 |
-0.077 |
-0.079 |
-0.080 |
-0.081 |
While the calculations generate lower results when the Farrell and
Shapiro model is used in place of the UPP* model introduced by
Werden and advocated by Schmalensee, they are still substantial
enough to generate a UPP index of 5 % or more for a broad range of
market structures. With margins set at .5, nine-to-eight
mergers would be problematic if efficiencies were ignored (see,
Table A2-a, above) and five-to-four mergers would be flagged with
an aggressive finding of 10 % efficiencies (see, Table A2-b,
above). Thus, both versions of the UPP analysis would
identify potential concerns in a broad collection of mergers.
Footnotes
1. For the EU, see Council
regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of January 20 2004 on the control of
concentrations between undertakings. The formal documents and
extensions are available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/legislation/regulations.html
(accessed on 27 June 2010). In the United States (US), the
controlling legal authority for structural merger analysis can be
found in Philadelphia National Bank, U. S. v. Philadelphia
National Bank, 374 U.S. 321 (1963),which created a presumption
of prime facie illegality for mergers involving firms controlling
"an undue percentage share of the relevant market and results in a
significant increase in concentration…" Id at
335. During the late 1960s, the Supreme Court applied the
presumption of illegality to firms with very small shares.
Over the next several decades, however, lower courts significantly
reduced the strength of the presumption and have tended to apply it
only for mergers involving very high market shares. ABA SECTION OF
ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS (6th ed. 2007) at
346-48.
2. Post-merger market share is
generally the key statistic in the EU, because dominant firms hold
large shares. Unilateral concerns, other than dominance, have
only been actionable in the EU since 2004 under the more general
substantial lessening of competition standard. M Bergman, M
Coate, M Jakobsson, and S Ulrick "Merger Enforcement in the
European Union and the United States: Just the Facts" (2010),
available at SSRN. Two statistics (the number of significant rivals
and the change in the Herfindahl) are commonly used in the
US. For significant rivals, see M Coate, "Unilateral Effects under
the Guidelines: Models, Merits, and Merger Policy"
(2009), available at SSRN. And for the change in the
Herfindahl, see G Werden and L Froeb, "Simulation as an Alternative
to Structural Merger Policy in Differentiated Products Industries",
in M Coate and A Kleit (eds), The Economics of the Antitrust
Process, (Boston, Kluwer Acad, 1996), 75.
3. See, for example, J Baker and C
Shapiro, "Reinvigorating Horizontal Merger Enforcement that has
Declined as a Result of Conservative Chicago Analysis", in R
Pitofsky (ed), Where the Chicago School Overshot the Mark,
(New York, Oxford University Press, 2008), 235.
4. While simulation structures have
been applied by the US enforcement agencies, the models have had no
success in the courts. See for example. U.S. v.
Oracle, 331 F. Supp. 2nd 1098 (N.D. Cal. 2004).
Likewise, simulation models influence EU-related enforcement
agencies, but appear not to play a role in the court cases. O
Budzinski and I Ruhmer, "Merger Simulation in
Competition Policy: A Survey" (2008), available at SSRN.
5. M. Coate and J. Fischer, "Daubert, Science and
Modern Game Theory: Implications for Merger Analysis"
forthcoming, Supreme Court Economic Review. Also
available at SSRN. Legal standards in the EU are less clear,
see. I. Lianos, "Judging Economists: Economic Expertise in
Competition Law Litigation", in Lianos and Kokkoris (eds), New
Challenges in EC Competition Law Enforcement, (Dordrecht,
Kluwer, 2009).
6. J Farrell and C Shapiro, "Antitrust
Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market
Definition" (2010) 10 THE B. E. JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL
ECONOMICS 1. A closely related version is available at
SSRN.
7. Ibid, 14 and 22; For
the discussion of UPP-based presumptions, see S Moresi,
"The Use of Upward Price Pressure Indicies in Merger Analysis"
(2010), Antitrust Source, and S Salop and S Moresi,
"Updating the Merger Guidelines: Comments," (2009).
8. For the most recent document in
United Kingdom. see
"Review of Merger Assessment Guidelines," April 14, 2010. For
the United States, see, "Horizontal
Merger Guidelines," April 20, 2010.
9. A quick look at equation 2 in
Farrell & Shapiro (supra n. 6) is illustrative.
If we put efficiencies to the side (i.e. set them to zero), then
any positive diversion from product 1 to 2 (i.e. any positive
cross-elasticity) produces a positive UPP.
10. Ibid, 9-10 and
22.
11. In the US, efficiencies must be
carefully vetted and only extraordinary efficiencies would be
expected to offset a particularly large anticompetitive effect (US
Merger Guidelines, 1997, section IV.) In the EU,
efficiencies are rarely considered in the final merger review
decision. See, Bergman et al. supra n. 2,
35-37.
12. Farrell and Shapiro
(supra n. 6) suggest that their technique serves "a very
different role than merger simulation" (29), but also note their
screening analysis could be revised as part of the full analysis on
the merits (22-23).
13. Examples include G Werden and L
Froeb, "The Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products
Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy" (1994) 10 Journal
of Law, Economics and Organization 407, J Hausman, and G
Leonard, "Economic Analysis of Differentiated Products Mergers
Using Real World Data" (1997) 5 George Mason Law Review
321, and G Werden, "Simulating the Effects of Differentiated
Products Mergers: A Practical Alternative to Structural Merger
Policy" (1997) 5 George Mason Law Review
363.
14. Ibid, Hausman and
Leonard, 331-334 and Werden and Froeb, 412-413.
15. Werden and Froeb, supra
n 2, 72. Of course, this result depends on the assumptions
for the relevant diversions.
16. Hausman and Leonard,
supra n 13, 331.
17. Budzinski and Ruhmer,
supra n 4, 17-24. The US Merger Commentaries also
endorse simulation. Federal Trade Commission and U.S. Department of
Justice, Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines
(2006): http://www.ftc.gov/os/2006/03/
CommentaryontheHorizontalMergerGuidelinesMarch2006.pdf at 14.
18. See for example, the simple
Lerner index model is rejected by the court in FTC v. Swedish
Match 131 F. Supp 2nd 151 (D.D.C. 2000) and the limitations of
more complex simulations addressed in U.S. v. Oracle, 331
F. Supp. 2nd 1098 (N.D. Cal. 2004). EU courts do not appear
to have addressed the issue. Budzinski and Ruhmer,
supra n 4.
19. For another list of draw-backs
see, Budzinski and Ruhmer, Ibid, 25-30
20. In effect, simulation has a
benchmarking problem, because it is unclear when the price effect
is large enough to be material. One interesting approach
would benchmark with social welfare. Werden and Froeb
(supra n 13, 419) note all hypothetical mergers in their
long distance service market would improve social welfare, except
for a deal between AT&T (long-distance) and MCI. In
effect, small price increases would be tolerated, because society
is better off with the merger. Large increases in average
industry prices would be problematic.
21. As Farrell and Shapiro
recognize, simulation results depend crucially on the assumed
structures for demand (which give rise to specific pass-through
values). See, Farrell and Shapiro supra n 6, 19-21
and P Crooke, L Froeb and S Tschantz, "Effects of Assumed Demand
Form on Simulated Postmerger Equilibria" (1999) 15 REVIEW OF
INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 205.
22. For example, Logit analysis
requires less data than AIDS analysis, but imposes assumptions on
the demand structure that may not be accurate.
23. For a discussion of estimation
problems in data rich environments, see D Hosken, D O'Brien,
D Scheffman, and M Vita, "Demand System
Estimation and its Application to Horizontal Merger Analysis",
Federal Trade Commission Working Paper, (2002).
24. These problems are discussed
with respect to critical loss analysis in M Coate and J Simons,
"Critical Loss: Modeling and Application Issues" (2009). Available at
SSRN.
25. For an initial attempt to
suggest modeling structures to address the impact of current
decisions on future returns, see J Farrell and C Shapiro,
"Improving Critical Loss" (2008) Antitrust
Source. When the inter-relationships are
customer-specific and each customer faces its own time series of
inter-related prices, mathematical "fixes" would require much more
assumed structure and therefore simulation-related tools offer
little, if any insight.
26. This evidence is summarized in
Coate and Fischer, supra n 5, 39-43.
27. See Farrell and Shapiro,
supra n 6, 11-13.
28. This intuition also helps to
explain why the model predicts that any horizontal merger will
raise price absent the presence of sufficient
efficiencies.
29. R Schmalensee,
"Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition"
(2009) 12 CPI ANTITRUST CHRONICLE 1 and G
Werden, "A Robust Test for Consumer Welfare Enhancing
Mergers Among Sellers in Differentiated Products" (1996) 44
Journal of Industrial Organization 409.
30. Farrell and Shapiro derive
firm-specific equations for use when market conditions preclude the
symmetry assumption. Farrell and Shapiro, supra n 6,
13. Our paper imposes symmetry assumptions for ease of
exposition. At this point, it retains the standard assumption
that diversion remains constant when rivals raise price.
31. Mathematically, the simulation
multiplies the price-cost margin and diversion for each cell and
then subtracts the product of the efficiency savings multiplied by
both, one minus the price-cost margin and one minus the diversion
ratio. The impact of a smaller "standard deduction" for
efficiencies can be computed by interpolating between the results
of the two tables. For example, given a price-cost margin of
.5 and a diversion ratio of .2, efficiencies of 5 % would lower the
UPP by 2 percentage points (.02) for Table 1-a and raise it by 2
percentage points for Table 1-b.
32. Technically, prices will not
change if the pass-through parameter equals zero. Thus,
special case situations may exist where positive UPP values will
not result in higher prices. Farrell and Shapiro provide a
formula for the pass-through and that formula can not be zero if
the demand curve is convex (the type of curve most economists
use). Farrell and Shapiro, supra n 6, 21.
33. Using simulated data and a
market definition concept that assumes firms are in the same market
if the diversion ratio exceeds 5 %, Das Varma shows the UPP
structure will generate concerns in 78 % of the sample, while the
35 % critical share (implicit in the US Merger Guidelines) creates
a concern in only 35% of the sample. Using a higher critical share
to reflect an EU concept of dominance would generate even fewer
concerns. G Das Varma, "Will the Use of the Upward Pricing
Pressure Test Lead to an Increase in the Level of Merger
Enforcement" (2009) 24 Antitrust 27.
34. Our computation assumes all
product is diverted to the firms' rivals. Diversion to
products outside the market can be represented by defining one
rival to be a composite good for consumer choices outside the
market. In the Appendix, an alternative approach is used, as
we allocate 20 % of the diversion to products outside the market
and assign 80 % of the diversion by market share. The two
methods can be compared by matching any column in Table A2-a with
the column from Table 2-a associated with one fewer rival.
(Table A2-b is not directly comparable to Table
2-b.)
35. Although it is conceivable that
not all equally situated competitors would be included in a market
technically defined under the Merger Guidelines, we are aware of no
instances where this has occurred in practice. Accordingly,
we believe the simulations in Table 2 provide valuable insight and
allow for good comparisons with historic levels of
enforcement. To the extent that the analyst can estimate
actual diversions, the simulations in Table 1 can be used
directly.
36. Bailey et al. focus on the 35 %
dominance standard and find that for share-based diversions, the
UPP policy could be more aggressive for margins above 32 % and less
aggressive for margins below 32 %. They also suggest an UPP
test could be difficult to implement. E Bailey, G Leonard, S
Olley, and L Wu, "Merger Screens: Market
Share-Based Approaches and 'Upward Pricing Pressure'
(2010) Antitrust Source.
37. For the EU, very few matters
were enforced when post-merger share fell below 40 % (equivalent to
5 equal pre-merger firms). See Bergman et al, supra
n 2, Table 6. Interestingly, the proposed UK guidelines seem
to address this problem by noting enforcement will be rare, when
either the merger can be characterized as 5-to-4 transaction or the
firm's post-merger share falls below 40 %. See, UK
Guidelines, supra n 8, 4.79. For details on the US policy, see
Coate, supra note 2, 38 (Table 2). Only 5 of the roughly
180 investigations focused on markets with 7 or more pre-merger
rivals (one actually enforced), hence these matters should not be
presumed problematic. Likewise, only 8 six-to-five
transactions were investigated, with enforcement in only two
matters. Core unilateral effects enforcement affects
three-to-two and two-to-one mergers. No rival-based or share
based restrictions were in the draft US Guidelines, supra
n 8.
38. In addition to Oracle, see
FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc, et al. 329 F. Supp. 2nd 109
(D.D.C., 2004) and FTC v. Foster, 2007-1, Trade Cas. (CCH)
¶ 75,725 (D. N.M., 2007).
39. Farrell and Shapiro present a
formulation of Salop and Moresi's UPP methodology which would
eliminate the efficiency standard deduction but replace it with a
deminimis tolerable level for a price effect. Farrell and
Shapiro, supra n 6, 23.
40. Farrell and Shapiro are
reluctant to consider their methodology to be a form of
simulation. Farrell and Shapiro, Ibid, 29.
However, the methodology, once generalized for pass-through rates,
easily generates a prediction of the mergers' price effect.
Epstein and Rubinfeld also see UPP as a special case of
simulation. R Epstein and D Rubinfeld, "Understanding
UPP" (2010) 10 The B. E. Journal of Theoretical
Economics.
41. Farrell and Shapiro observe that
estimation of the pass-though might be extremely difficult and thus
the analyst might end up assuming a value. Ibid,
20-23. (The formula in equation 5 is adjusted to (1)
represent symmetry and (2) consider efficiencies captured by the
merger partner in the analysis as detailed in Section III,
above. Thus it is not technically a Farrell and Shapiro
model, but follows Farrell and Shapiro in declining to track the
full equilibrium price and thus we feel it is appropriate to keep
the designation.)
42. If the other parameters of the
model could be defined for a sample of cases, it might be possible
to estimate G from historical enforcement data.
43. Schmalensee, supra n
29, 5. Consider Schamalensee's PCAL to equal Farrell and Shapiro's
G and then rewrite one half as R and divide it across the equation
to basically obtain the Farrell and Shapiro result. The only
difference is the inverse of the difference between one and the
diversion ratio. Schmalensee cautions against a naïve
application of his simulation formula. And he notes that he
assumes away effects driven by responses from other
competitors. It is unclear if Schmalensee sees the formula as
a useful structure for merger simulation.
44. Farrell and Shapiro,
supra n 6, 24. Farrell and Shapiro trace the
alternative analysis to Werden, supra n 29.
45. The result for UPP-FS can be
read off of Table 1-b, although it will be necessary to divide by
two to adjust for the pass-through parameter. The UPP-S
result will be 33 % higher when the margin is set at .5. In
the symmetric model, both the merged firms will raise price by
these amounts. This result requires the assumption that
diversion ratios do not change when both firms raise price.
If this assumption is not acceptable, the simulation should focus
on a single firm price increase.
46. Different analysts can also
generate different results by using different pass-through
statistics.
47. For a discussion on the
implications of dynamic competition for market definition, see
Coate and Simons, supra n 24.
48. As discussed in Coate and
Fischer, supra n 5, merger simulation models merely
present what might happen after a merger. Without some type
of evidence to confirm the prediction, the model merely states a
hypothesis.
49. The UK draft appears to touch on
natural experiments at 4.12 (and 4.89), while hot documents seem
covered at 4.8 and customer complaints at 4.9. For the US,
natural experiments show up at 2.1.1 and 2.12, while hot documents
are relevant at 2.2.1 and customer complaints at 2.2.2. See
Draft Guidelines, supra n 8.
50. Some insights on this issue can
be drawn from FTC data. Coate identifies a sample of 75
analyses (with three or more pre-merger significant rivals) in
which the FTC undertook a unilateral effects investigation.
(M Coate, "The Enhanced
UPP Screen, Merging Markets into the UPP Methodology" (2010),
17, available at SSRN. Of these matters, 31 were
closed. A review of the files indicates that repositioning
was an issue in nine of these 31 closed matters. Three of the
nine cases also exhibited findings of relatively easy entry and
another four had six or more pre-merger rivals. Thus,
standing alone, repositioning is rarely used to justify closing a
unilateral effects investigation.